CLICK THE SPONSORS' LOGOS FOR THE LATEST SPECIALS !
Maxis Solutions
HALE-IAW PART 5: WEIGHTING THE INDEX & ENGAGING THE PUBLIC
Home | Index |O'view |Glossary | Part 1 | Part 2 | Part 3 | Part 4 | Part 5 | References | Appendix on Method 
	 Acknowledgements | Boxes - 10 | Figures - 11 | Tables - 18 | Disclaimer | Copyright

PART FIVE: WEIGHTING THE INDEX & ENGAGING THE PUBLIC 

	13. Weighting the index  
		a	Alternative weightings, contributions to improving
			the index and engaging the public
		b	Possiblities for the Future 

13. Weighting the index 

The results produced by a composite index are heavily influenced by how its 
constituent parts are aggregated together. 

Using GDP as a starting point to weighting our index is not to embrace the
crude cynicism of money values. 

Rather we have done so because of the complete lack of any other coherent 
place to start. 

Indeed, the only real alternative we have seen seems to involve a cascade of 
arbitrary decisions that amount to little more than a shrug of the shoulders 
and a resigned decision to ‘split the difference’ and plump for some kind of 
improvised equality among domains of wellbeing at every turn (which itself 
ends in paradox as each sub-domain is itself dominated by this hankering 
to split the difference among different measures – see Box 3). 

Even the SSF Commission, which spent some time setting out its concerns 
with arbitrary weightings and aggregations, ultimately dodged the question, 
recommending that statistical agencies invest in a number of scalar measures 
to allow them to answer different questions. 

For example, these could supplement average progress measures such as
the HDI with other measures that tracked the relative importance of domains
to individuals (such as the U-index and equivalent income approaches). 

It is easy to offer examples that make a mockery of any weightings chosen. 

For some people one weighting will be vastly more important than others. 

Weighting the importance of health from nine per cent to 18 per cent of the 
index will clearly underestimate its importance to a gravely ill person. 

Likewise rating the quality of governance at some even lower figure would
underestimate its importance to someone whose livelihood was ruined by 
poor governance. 

But, as compelling as they are, individual examples like this do not illustrate 
the inadequacy of the weightings chosen, so much as illustrate the nature of
the index itself as a single index that must meet everyone’s needs as best 
it can. 

Seen in this light, it does not seem so far-fetched to say that the relative 
importance some aspect of national wellbeing might be approximated by 
the weight it is accorded in national decisions to spend economic resources 
on it with individual decisions and the collective decisions of governments 
each playing a role in the ultimate allocation of resources. 

And, of course, one can also adjust the weightings to reflect ad hoc 
considerations – which is indeed what we have done in proposing calibrations
for this index. 

a	Alternative weightings, contributions to improving the index and engaging 
	the public 

Whatever we have to say in this report, some others will have different ideas. 

Thus, though part of the exercise has been to come up with a unique set of 
weights by which to generate a single index, that is no reason that others might 
not profitably – for themselves or for others – propose different weightings. 

Especially given modern technology, it is a relatively easy matter to give users 
of the index the ability to vary the weightings as they see fit, as has been done 
with the recent OECD Better Life Index. 

This could also assist in engaging the public in the exercise. 

One could take things further. 

As well as allowing individual website visitors to vary the weightings, one might 
encourage public deliberation on the weightings. 

And one might do it not just via blogs and online engagement, but also in 
consensus conferences in which particular community members, experts and 
representatives of community groups might deliberate together.(53) 

The task of weighting the index would be instructive for school or university 
assignments helping participants to explore the intellectual challenge and 
conceptual and ethical dilemmas of constructing such an index. 

This could lead them to explore and understand their own values – and the 
values of the community in so doing. 

There are ways that the index could be extended.

One might conduct outreach to universities to get advanced undergraduate or 
postgraduate students to propose improvements to our methodology. 

If for instance Fairfax would like to put up a prize of (say) $2,000 to the 
undergraduate student proposing the best improvement to the construction 
and maintenance of the index, Lateral Economics would be happy to make 
an equal contribution in kind – for instance by promoting the prize within
universities and schools and reading entries and judging the winners of the 
prize. 

It would also be worthwhile to develop by similar means a more detailed and 
considered inventory of causes of avoidable suffering that might form part 
of an index of Gross National Suffering, which itself might play a role in 
the nation’s life in assisting that struggle by which, in Denis Healey’s
memorable words quoting Kolakowski, we go about “eroding by inches the 
conditions which produce avoidable suffering”. 

(53)

The ANDI project is intending to conduct detailed consultation processes with Australians to determine which aspects of wellbeing 
are most important to us, and use these to choose indicators and weight them accordingly.

The new state planning approach in various states such as South Australia tends to take this approach with heavy consultation
with the community on the targets to be met, but there is no explicit reduction of the targets into a single composite target. 

These weightings produce the index, which is tracked in the chart below 
from June 2005 until June 2010. 

Figure 10:HALE Index of Wellbeing

As will be seen, the HALE Index of Wellbeing is more volatile than either GDP 
or NNI. 

This reflects three factors: 

1	the volatility of some of its constituents (particularly human capital 
	and to a lesser extent unemployment and underemployment); 

2	the lower frequency of important updates in the raw data; and 

3	some of the more volatile constituents are large, particularly the 
	elements of human capital. 

Over the five year period plotted above, the main driver of the HALE Index’s 
deviations from NNI from which it is built, is the growth of human capital. 

This is not surprising since our methodology suggests that this is the biggest 
aspect of our wellbeing that NNI fails to capture. 

The period charted in Figure 10 begins, with an unusually low human capital 
contribution from schooling at the beginning of the period. 

This artificially depresses the 2005 HALE Index and similarly exaggerates the 
growth in human capital over the period. 

Nevertheless the proportion of tertiary qualified people in the workforce rises, 
particularly in the middle of the period and this is a major factor in driving the 
surge from below NNI to a figure that almost matches GDP in the middle of 
the period. 

Put another way, the surge in human capital over this period adds almost 
as much capital to our economy as the depreciation of the physical capital 
stock of plant and equipment, which is the principal difference between 
NNI and GDP except where there are strong movements in the terms of trade. 

Thereafter the HALE Index broadly tracks NNI though at a higher level 
reflecting continuing higher growth of human capital. 

Because it is built on NNI, the HALE Index captures the terms of trade
‘whipsaw’ at the time of the GFC and in fact accentuates it slightly 
because the HALE Index responds more to changes in unemployment 
and underemployment than NNI or GDP. 

Table 18:The HALE Index of Wellbeing 2005 and 2010.

b	Possibilities for the future 

We would like to develop and extend the HALE Index of Wellbeing in the future. 

Areas that we hope to improve include: 

1	The parameterisation of the relationship between income distribution 
	and welfare; 

2	Better understanding the relationship between the quality of 
	employment and life satisfaction; 

3	Accounting for co-morbidities between wellbeing variables, such as the 
	increased prevalence of obesity and mental illness among people who 
	are also unemployed or with low incomes; 

4	Extending the calibration of factors like child development and social 
	capital to a larger share of the population than those who are at risk. 

5	The issues discussed in the Appendix on Method on page 82. 


Home | Index |O'view |Glossary | Part 1 | Part 2 | Part 3 | Part 4 | Part 5 | References | Appendix on Method 
	 Acknowledgements | Boxes - 10 | Figures - 11 | Tables - 18 | Disclaimer | Copyright

























































































































































































































































THD T 2012/08/14 12:00 - 12:29 Rendering content for Web-page THD T 2012/08/14 12:30 - 12:51 Preparing Web-page THD T 2012/08/14 12:51 - 13:09 Checking Web-page for launch on Internet































































































<